Efficient scale and scope of business models used in municipal solid waste management

Massimo Beccarello (Department of Business and Law, University of Milan-Bicocca, Milan, Italy)
Giacomo Di Foggia (Department of Business and Law, University of Milan-Bicocca, Milan, Italy)

European Journal of Management and Business Economics

ISSN: 2444-8494

Article publication date: 3 April 2023

Issue publication date: 7 December 2023

1069

Abstract

Purpose

The paper aims to compare the efficiency of alternative municipal solid waste (MSW) management business models: a single provider against multiple providers.

Design/methodology/approach

In this paper the drivers of MSW management costs are analysed to test the impact of the scale and scope of MSW management services on the average cost. While the business-as-usual scenario foresees a single provider, the alternative scenario foresees multiple providers.

Findings

Based on the empirical data on municipal waste management costs, on average, the size and the average cost of the service are inversely related. This trend is supported using sub-sets defined by the quantity of waste managed. Multiple factors aid in explaining this result, and among others, due to scale and scope, factors such as transition costs increase with the number of players running different services.

Practical implications

The provision of public services of economic interest should favour the participation of more companies wherever possible to the extent that social surplus is produced. However, pursuing this principle to the detriment of efficient service delivery is not ideal. This paper demonstrated that a single-provider waste management business model is efficient under specific conditions, as in this article.

Originality/value

This paper presents an original research methodology for comparatively analysing waste management service efficiency in urban areas and provides adequate evidence using alternative measures of costs according to the phase of the waste management chain, the scale and ultimately the scope of MSW management services.

研究目的

本學術論文擬比較另類的都市固體廢物管理模式的效率, 比較的對像是:單一服務提供者和多個提供服務者。

研究設計/方法/理念

研究人員分析都市固體廢物管理成本和價格的動因, 以測試有關的管理服務之規模和範圍對平均成本的影響。若在一切照常的情況下, 我們會預見單一服務提供者, 唯在不尋常的情況下, 我們則會預見多個提供服務者。

研究結果

根據都市廢物管理價格和成本上的實證數據, 平均而言, 服務的規模與其平均成本是成反比的。我們使用了以所處理之廢物量來界定的子集來支持這趨勢。多重因素會幫助解釋和說明這研究結果, 其中包括:因規模和範圍的關係, 諸如過度成本等的因素, 會按著提供各種不同服務的主要參與者的數目而增加。

實務方面的啟示

在能達創造社會剩餘的前題下, 會帶來經濟效益之公共服務的提供, 應有利於在可行範圍內有更多公司的參與; 但如果實行這原則而因此有損於服務提供的效率的話, 則這是不理想的。本文展示了在特定的情況下, 單一服務提供者的廢物管理商業模式是高效率的, 本文已說明這些特定情況。

研究的原創性/價值

本文為以比較分析法去探討城市地區廢物管理服務的效率、提出了一個新穎的研究方法, 並根據廢物管理鏈的階段、都市固體廢物管理服務的規模、以及最終其範圍, 考慮了成本和價格的另類測量方法, 繼而提供充分的證據, 以支持這些測量方法。

Keywords

Citation

Beccarello, M. and Di Foggia, G. (2023), "Efficient scale and scope of business models used in municipal solid waste management", European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 32 No. 4, pp. 492-508. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJMBE-09-2022-0271

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2023, Massimo Beccarello and Giacomo Di Foggia

License

Published in European Journal of Management and Business Economics. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Public services of general economic interest are fundamental to the nation's economic development and significantly impact social welfare (Boggio, 2016). The operational efficiency of the municipal solid waste (MSW) management industry has become increasingly significant for achieving sustainable development objectives (Zorpas, 2020). Business and governance models of MSW management need to evolve towards efficiency levels compatible with the achievement of economic and environmental objectives (Kaza et al., 2018). Research has exposed the critical need for assessing different models of governance and organisation, and entrusting services for the governance and delivery of public services (Soukopová et al., 2017). Trade-offs between the competitive dimensions in industrial structures characterised by imperfect competition must also be considered.

Typically, local authorities can choose between three models and procedures: entrusting the service to third parties through public procedures, the provision of the services through hybrid public-private firms and in-house provision. Free market and competition rules apply to actors entrusted with providing public services for economic interests as long as these rules do not prevent them from fulfilling their general mission (European Commission, 2022).

Additionally, the principle that underpins European competition and public procurement legislation since the introduction of Directive (2014)/24/EU is important, which is to encourage small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) to participate in public procurement and, thereby, in the provision of public services. However, this principle can be abandoned by considering integrated utilities, which can provide more services at various stages of the chain, owing to the economies of scale and scope resulting from their production efficiency. Sub-dividing large municipalities can be assumed to lead to greater competition, fostering growth among service providers (Sarra et al., 2020). However, on the contrary, a recent empirical study focused on Barcelona revealed that multiple firms can strategically interact to maximise producer surplus at the expense of social welfare (Bel and Sebő, 2021).

MSW management can be regarded as an industry with two or more intertwined phases. The market structure in the first phase is mainly labour-intensive, while the second phase is capital-intensive and supported by enabling infrastructure, such as waste treatment plants. Both phases are subject to the risk of market failure, and in certain circumstances, the market can effectively manage one or more services (Di Foggia and Beccarello, 2018).

The industrial organisation of the collection phase often involves local monopoly configurations justified by the economies of scale resulting from the size of the service and its economies of scope (AGCM - Italian Competition Authority, 2016). Much has been written regarding the existence of scale economies, an important issue with some consensus (Callan and Thomas, 2001), as confirmed in previous analyses that also found scale economies and some efficiency differences between public and private providers (Tickner and Mcdavid, 1986). Early research in the field of economies of scale focused on the inter-relationships of scale, market structure and costs, with scattered evidence in the beginning, based on the little evidence of the existence of certain scale economies (Stevens, 1978).

In this regard, the more recent findings on economies of scale have provided mixed results. For example, a recent study found that less than half (40.4% of the municipalities evaluated), presented negative economies of scale (Llanquileo-Melgarejo and Molinos-Senante, 2021). Another study underscores the drivers of costs under alternative cost definitions (Di Foggia and Beccarello, 2020). Similarly, a third article concluded that population and size are important factors for scale economies, and the implication is uncertain (Wowrzeczka, 2021). This uncertainty is partly due to information asymmetries that complicate comparative analyses. Another factor that concurs with mixed results is the unit of analysis.

Indeed, many studies aimed at understanding the economies of scope in MSW management by focussing on the input factors of firms and very different output variables, failing to differentiate among collection costs, total costs and treatment costs or using per capita cost against costs per unit of waste.

Scale economies in a public service of general interest such as waste management should be evaluated from the perspective of the contracting authority, paying more attention to exogenous factors affecting the organisation of the service that must be used at the same level as the input factors of firms. Indeed, failing to consider the above may result in formally correct results but be biased in practice if the sub-additivity of costs is not considered. Consequently, the contracting authorities may decide it inappropriate to divide the contract into lots to avoid the risk of rendering the execution of the contract excessively technically difficult or expensive and because co-ordinating the different contractors for the lots could risk undermining the proper execution of the contract.

Some scholars have empirically evaluated the impact of different regulated business models on MSW management and suggested that their efficiency can be increased by limiting the size of these service areas so that the system encourages large service providers to compete for service allocation in a large number of small areas, thus intensifying the positive effects of market competition (Sarra et al., 2020). However, it could be argued that reducing the size of the areas that can be allocated to a single firm may promote anti-competitive strategies aimed at creating divisions between several theoretically competing operators.

Strengthening market competition and realising economies of scale by integrating organisations (and thus reducing the number of individual economic actors) can be considered appropriate choices for achieving economic and environmental efficiency. First, this idea is supported based on an econometric model that identifies the main determinants of service costs. Then, the focus was on the analysis of multiple case studies, using a sample consisting of the ten most populous Italian cities. Third, a single case comparing a “business-as-usual” model involving a single economic actor with an alternative scenario consisting of four firms was analysed.

Evidence suggests that as the size of the service increases, the average cost tends to decrease. The case study confirms the presence of economies of scale, resulting from the specific factors employed in the production of the service.

The rest of the article is organised as follows. Section 2 presents a literature review and reports on the previously published studies that have explained some of the aspects analysed in this article. Section 3 describes the context and research design as well as the data collection process and the variables in this study. Section 4 presents the results of the econometric analysis and case studies. Section 5 discusses the main considerations and implications arising from the findings. The final section concludes.

2. Background and literature

The complexity of the waste management (WM) industry raises concerns about the technologies it relies upon and the sustainability of its business models (Björklund et al., 1999), which also depend on how contracts between MSW management providers and institutions are structured (Walls, 2005). In light of the challenging environmental goals, the efficiency of MSW management business models has become an increasingly important concern (Kinnaman, 2009); thus, their sustainability as well as their emergent role in local communities is critical (Avilés-Palacios and Rodríguez-Olalla, 2021; Esmaeilian et al., 2018). As such, the relationship between efficiency and economies of scale is attracting more attention at both the political and the organisational levels. Accordingly, the number of studies on the cost of MSW management has grown, such as the analysis of the cost functions (Bohm et al., 2010) or the cost of recycling environmental policies (Da Cruz et al., 2014).

Previous literature has focused on the determinants of demand for MSW management services (Diaz-Farina et al., 2020), organisational forms and modes of supply (Zhang et al., 2015), policy implications (Goddard, 1995), cost structures (Callan and Thomas, 2001; Pérez-López et al., 2016) and the need to develop strategies to achieve sustainability goals. Regarding sustainability goals, geopolitical contingencies make it difficult to reach the binding agreements and credible commitments made by policymakers (Darus et al., 2020).

Different approaches have been proposed to analyse the economic efficiency of MSW collection firms. For example, a recent study identified a relation between costs and environmental efficiency, although this relationship is non-linear, as a rise in the separated waste collection rate increases total costs by a less-than-proportional amount, which provides evidence of the existence of economies of scale (Bartolacci et al., 2019).

Economic and technical efficiency have emerged as prominent factors in explaining costs (lo Storto, 2021). Given the increasing pressure governments face to increase cost efficiency, they may transfer waste disposal services to private firms (Jacobsen et al., 2013). This possibility has raised the dilemma of whether for-profit enterprises are compatible with outcomes that maximise social welfare (Kinnaman, 2009); the available findings are mixed (Bel and Fageda, 2010; Simões et al., 2012).

Empirical evidence based on the existing MSW management business models is important, as it shows how economic and political factors exert different impacts on MSW management via both private and public firms (Plata-Díaz et al., 2014). Other studies indicate that private MSW management operators are not necessarily better performers than public firms (Bel and Fageda, 2010).

Additionally, firm size, inter-firm relations and alternative technologies, as found in studies on green reverse logistics technology (Mugoni et al., 2023), can be argued to significantly impact MSW management strategies (Lombrano, 2009). Considering that the size of firms that perform public services may correspond to a greater propensity to innovate, it is intuitive that advancing MSW business models can improve the net economic benefit they provide (Marashlian and El-Fadel, 2005). Broadly speaking, business models and MSW management methods, such as the organisation of collection services, have received limited attention (Guerrini et al., 2017).

These methods are crucial because they significantly impact the organisation of work (Allesch and Brunner, 2014), and both controllable and non-controllable factors can significantly impact the costs of MSW management (De Jaeger and Rogge, 2013).

Furthermore, the way the service is provided, and the size and density of the population also affect the costs of MSW management due to economies of scale (De Jaeger et al., 2011). The characteristics of the waste produced also play an important role (Chifari et al., 2017; Greco et al., 2015). Worth remembering is that morphological and geographical factors (Passarini et al., 2011), socio-economic conditions (Mazzanti et al., 2008), and policies and legal frameworks (Benito-López et al., 2011) are also central to forming cost structures. Environmental objectives (Beccarello and Di Foggia, 2016), production technologies (Swart and Groot, 2015; Tisserant et al., 2017), and the use of waste management facilities (Chu et al., 2019) also play a role in this process.

With respect to how the competitive environment and business strategies influence agility, adaptability and alignment – which are linked, as reported by a recent study (Garrido-Vega et al., 2021) – there is a paucity of articles focussing on the strategic behaviour of MSW management firms. Some studies have drawn conclusions concerning the degree and type of market competition (Bel and Sebő, 2020, 2021).

3. Methodology

3.1 Context

The waste management industry is a hybrid, regulated and market-driven sector as the main activities in the collection phase are often allocated to legal monopolies, whereas those in the treatment phase, for example of waste electrical and electronic equipment (Roy et al., 2022), can mostly be fulfilled by the market.

Therefore, analysing economic and environmental efficiency based on identifying economies of scale and scope is particularly complicated. As evidence of this, the results in the previous literature do not necessarily reach the same conclusions. There are many reasons for this. Studies have been conducted in different disciplines; also, the type of cost analysed as a dependent variable (e.g. total costs, costs of separated collection, costs of non-segregated collection and sales prices) differs depending on the context. The unit of analysis may contribute to the variance in the results, and the analysed phase plays a large role in this phenomenon.

We refer to the combination of the transaction cost approach, economies of scale and the competitive aspects that are becoming increasingly important in defining how the MSW management industry should function.

The idea of transaction costs is applied in many contexts, from simple situations to more general ideas that consider various methods for allocating resources and coordinating economic activity (Klaes, 2016). Transaction costs are a necessary first step in separating the factor market from the product market. It may be impossible to distinguish between markets in service industries characterised by a supply chain with a significant number of suppliers. Therefore, distinguishing one organisation from another is often difficult when decisions are contractually binding. Furthermore, transaction costs are often difficult to measure and separate by type (Cheung, 2016).

Transaction costs, like production costs, are a wide-ranging designation for a heterogeneous assortment of inputs and transaction functions that may show diminishing, constant or increasing returns; in general, economies of scale are often pronounced. Compared to a theoretical state without transaction costs, transaction costs inevitably reduce social welfare due to the loss of allocative efficiency they incur. Efficiency problems also arise in a more general context. As complicated transactions may include multi-lateral contracts with many parties, transaction costs tend to increase (Niehans, 2016).

Figure 1 is a theoretical approximation of how transaction costs can be delineated within the two-stage waste chain. Figure 1a represents an integrated provider operating at both levels of the supply chain. Figure 1b represents a market structure characterised by several firms that, as in the case of an integrated system, operate in several stages of the supply chain. In this case, the concessionaire must manage contracts with some firms, which, as it is a public service, must be provided at the same level of quality for all citizens. Figure 1c represents a market structure in which multiple firms specialise in services that take place in only one phase of the supply chain. In this case, a similar situation to that described in Figure 1b arises; however, not only is a coordination point necessary at a horizontal level in the same phase of the supply chain but also an additional element is added consisting of the provision of a service in only one phase of the supply chain. Figure 1d generalises different configurations. Please note that the cases presented in Figure 1 do not include all possible configurations.

The phases that make up this network industry as well as the main functions – and consequently the different services within the two resulting phases – can be seen in Figure 2.

Figure 2 shows operations in one or more phases. Figure 2 also includes an additional phase (the generation of urban waste), as it is increasingly important in organising citizen activities that extend beyond mere communication and awareness campaigns. The two arrows are significant. The arrow in the upper part of Figure 2 shows the path of waste; that in the lower part reflects the circular economic process.

Therefore, the relationship between efficiency and economies of scale is more important at both policy and market organisation levels, and thus, the number of relevant studies on the cost of MSW management has increased (Pérez-López et al., 2016; Sarra et al., 2017). The economic literature has often focused on the determinants of demand for MSW management services (Diaz-Farina et al., 2020), organisational forms and mode of supply (Zhang et al., 2015), and cost structures of MSW management (Callan and Thomas, 2001; Pérez-López et al., 2016) as well as the need to develop MSW management strategies to achieve sustainability goals.

3.2 Research design

The analyses were developed at two levels to increase the robustness of the results; two research questions were developed to investigate this topic.

RQ1.

What is the relation between the size of the service and the cost? An econometric analysis based on 54% of Italian municipalities was developed to identify the impact of the determinants of MSW management costs. Then, a sensitivity analysis of different samples was performed by dividing the sample into 3, 5, 10, 15 and 20 sub-samples. The hypothesis is an inverse relationship between scale and cost.

RQ2.

Which factors impact the optimisation of MSW management services? A case study was used to test the best option between assigning MSW management to a single firm or dividing the city into four lots and assigning the service to four firms. The observed cost was reclassified, based on the 56 sub-services (see Annex 1 for additional details) that constitute the service. An alternative scenario in which four firms provide MSW management services was simulated for comparative purposes.

This scenario first considered the organisational structure of the incumbent, which is divided into four branches referring to four sub-areas of the city of Milan. Then, a hypothetical total cost was calculated, based on the four existing operating divisions. The case study analysis aimed to shed light on the operating and organisational factors that have received little attention thus far in MSW research on scale and scope. The hypothesis is that a single contractor is expected to provide MSW management services more efficiently due to organisational issues and transaction costs.

3.3 Data collection and variables

The official data from the municipal waste cadastre published by the Italian national environmental protection institute (ISPRA) and openly accessible from the ISPRA web portal were used to run the analyses. The cadastre database contains data referring to the cost of MSW management, treatment options and waste production at the municipality level. Similarly, the data available in the public balance sheets of the city of Milan were used. Only municipalities with available data were included in the sample. The morphological and geographical data were retrieved from the Italian Statistics Institute portal, which contains the data on all Italian municipalities, which are publicly available for download. We aimed to increase the robustness of the analysis at the sub-sample level by rerunning the econometric analysis using comparable municipalities by size, as reported in the sensitivity analysis.

Table 1 contains the key statistics for the variables used in this analysis. The data refer to 2019, as it was the last available certified period at the time of data collection (see Figure 3).

4. Empirical evidence

Figure 4 shows the relationship between costs and the scale of services. As this relationship is influenced by organisational dynamics, the scale of services and costs appear inversely related.

4.1 Econometric analysis

Applying the model in Equation (1) and shown in Table 2, the determinants of the variations in MSW management costs with respect to organisational size were examined. Other conditions, such as the specific demographic and morphological characteristics of the territory (which, together with the industrial structure of the waste treatment phase, influence MSW management costs), were considered. Furthermore, whether the average cost of MSW management tends to decrease as the population increases was checked. In Equation (1), the dependent variable is the average cost of management (Eurocents per kg), while the independent variables are the population, size of the area in which the service is provided, percentage of separated collection, population density and altitude, as well as being a coastal municipality or otherwise.

Equation (1): Econometric analysis

(1)log(cost)=α+β1log(msw)+β2log(area)+β3log(sor)+β4log(dens)+β5log(alt)+β6cost+ε

The equation is reiterated in three variants, as shown in Table 2, which contains three columns corresponding to the three models, specifically.

  1. Model 1 refers to the total cost of the MSW management service;

  2. Model 2 refers to the management costs of sorted waste;

  3. Model 3 refers to the management costs of residual waste.

Regarding Model 1, Figure 5 shows the results of the sensitivity analysis performed to test the robustness of the results.

Considering the results shown in Table 3, it appears that an inverse relation between the scale of the service and the cost exists in the types of costs considered when developing the three models.

Figure 5 presents a sensitivity analysis of the elasticity of the average cost of production in terms of the amount of waste handled, which seems to confirm the general hypothesis that asserts that the MSW sector tends to be characterised by economies of scale. The coefficient for the full population was − 0.46. As the number of intervals increases, the coefficient, although based on limited data, tends to increase. At this point, we conduct a comparative evaluation of the cost of collection and transport of the main Italian cities, which represents the segment of urban MSW management most affected by the dynamics of company organisation and the consequent optimisation of services. Such an analysis allows a comparative assessment based on a scenario defined by sub-dividing the city of Milan into four sub-areas to simulate the organisation of MSW management services and examine the impact of transaction costs.

Given that the analysis is limited to the main Italian cities and a small number of observations, we proceed with a bottom-up approach that reconstructs the costs using information published on the website of the Municipality of Milan, including the 2019 financial statements of the incumbent, explanatory notes, and the service contract between the Municipality and the incumbent. The scenario in which four firms provide MSW management services would imply a 6% increase in production costs compared to that of the incumbent.

5. Discussion

Economies of scale can play a significant role in defining business models (Di Foggia and Beccarello, 2021) even though they may seemingly conflict with the common knowledge that policymakers should favour SMEs in the provision of public services to create new opportunities and support the growth of SMEs, which in turn can make a significant economic contribution. It is worth emphasising that the involvement of SMEs in public procurement allows contracting authorities to broaden their base of potential suppliers and to benefit from the increased competition for public contracts. However, such positive externalities in terms of efficiency and market development gains vanish in certain circumstances. Indeed, the arguments regarding the presence of economies shall be contextualised to fit with the cases. Considering that a few studies have stated that the existence of scale economies, to a certain level, does not indicate that it can be generalised to all cities. In fact, most studies have analysed samples only with no or just a few large municipalities. In contrast, this article deeply analyses the MSW cost structure in a 1.38-million inhabited city, suggesting that the MSW service is large and complex enough to require specific analyses.

In cities where public or private incumbent monopolies have long-run MSW management services, policymakers should not allow for excessive exemptions, such as splitting a city's area into several sub-areas to allow more firms to participate in MSW management. Nevertheless, it is possible to argue that splitting the municipal area into several sub-areas or the MSW management service into sub-services each, or some of them corresponding to many, may encourage anti-competitive strategies. This action limits the number of lots in which a single economic operator can run the service and may even lead to covert agreements between competitors, which would in turn worsen social welfare, for example, due to transaction costs (Cheung, 2016; DaSilva and Trkman, 2014) that have received little attention in MSW management studies.

Analysing the city of Milan enabled the determination of the efficiency of the business model by including costs sourced from public information regarding the incumbent, and the results conveyed that a single firm was more efficient than four firms. The main reasons highlighted include the differences, especially regarding the separated collection of materials (e.g. street-sweeping activities and bin-emptying activities), given that the production factors, employees, means of production and containers required are proportional in the two scenarios analysed in this article. However, this study found several issues related to transaction costs. Furthermore, the results indicate that the incumbent is more efficient from an economic standpoint.

The services causing the greatest cost burden are those related to collection, which include the sorting of bulky waste, durables, batteries, pharmaceuticals and spent toner cartridges, the collection of residual and differentiated waste with dedicated containers, the collection of residual and differentiated waste in cemeteries, the cleaning of markets, the collection and disposal of small items containing asbestos, the separated collection of used clothing, the separated collection of used oil and some sweeping activities such as cleaning the banks of watercourses, collecting leaves, cleaning tree rows and their areas, mowing and weeding pavements, and washing tunnels, arcades and sub-ways. Similarly, other activities, including on-demand services, have been shown to experience a significant increase in costs. Some production factors are not divisible or shareable between firms, which would entail the duplication of that production factor and therefore its cost.

Evidence suggests that entrusting MSW management services to a single firm may positively affect the community given the potential cost savings (−6%) and, thereby, the waste tax that citizens pay to finance them. The main drivers increasing production costs are the need for personnel and means of production – namely, vehicles – to provide the same level of service if they were to be provided by several firms. The above results are correlated with strategic management and uncertainty-coping strategies, given that uncertainty plays a substantial role in strategic decision-making processes and increases the risk and ambiguity of innovation (Beraha et al., 2018), which is needed to improve the performance of the MSW management industry.

Interestingly, a recent study focussing on the city of Barcelona showed that dividing the region into four lots discriminated in terms of quality and, furthermore, differentiated service quality. The study analysed the effects of competition by focussing on the strategic behaviour of firms and illustrated the incentive to strategically determine the quality, based on the operating distance from competitors, which is an approximation of competitive pressure. This is, therefore, a risk if the principle of universality of service quality is to be respected. It is important to avoid triggering strategic behaviours that increase service quality only in the most relevant and directly comparable areas (Bel and Sebő, 2021).

However, both positive and negative aspects should be noted to exist even when a single firm provides the service, as shown in Table 3.

The results also provide information on the compatibility of such strategic behaviour of firms with the principle of universality of service. This is an essential element and a principle that cannot be derogated from and a risk that may emerge. A further risk lies in the information asymmetries between local authorities and contractors, which could reduce the efforts of the latter in neighbourhoods farthest from those where there is more competition.

The main contribution of this paper is threefold. From a theoretical perspective, it summarises the previous literature on economies of scale and scope in MSW management and provides thought-provoking results that further the discussion on competitive policy and the regulation of public services. From a managerial perspective, the results offer new insights into critical organisational and operating factors that may emerge in running such services, which, due to transaction and other costs, may lead to sub-optimal levels of output and economic inefficiency. This paper also has policy implications given that the abovementioned considerations can serve as a reference for public decision-makers in designing municipal strategies that consider economic and social welfare outcomes. Managerial and practical perspectives are also straightforward for both bit utilities and SMEs, which shall analyse in detail the organisational and transaction costs they may experience in running this service in complex circumstances.

Our results also suggest that additional research is needed to evaluate the relation between scale and MSW management costs, which is a public service of general interest. Its effectiveness should be evaluated from a contracting authority – often municipality – perspective, not only from the firm perspective, paying more attention to the exogenous factors affecting the organisation of the service. Indeed, failing to consider the above may result in formally correct results but bias in practice if the sub-additivity of costs is not considered. In fact, a paradox may emerge. When analysing samples of firms the results of relatively small-scale economies may suggest the optimal size that, if put into practice in relatively large cities, resulted in multiple firms operating conjunctively, paving the way to transition costs and organisational failures that lead to negative externalities: one pitfall relates to costs, and the other downside refers to different quality levels that may occur in different parts of the cities because the service is run by different companies, and other hypothetical problems emerge in the potential strategic behaviour of firms and difficulties in regulating more firm issues.

6. Conclusion

This paper investigates the scale and scope of MSW management business models in terms of their economic efficiency to provide empirical evidence to support both the debate and the design of competitive waste management policy strategies. On one hand, it is generally recognised that the broad participation of SMEs in the provision of public services is a public policy goal. On the other hand, monopolistic competition outperforms other models in certain circumstances – for example, in that of integrated utilities, which can provide more services at more stages of the supply chain, owing to economies of scale and scope resulting from their optimised and streamlined production models.

A novel contribution of this paper is in its effort to analyse and test the same hypothesis across different conditions. From a national perspective, based on an econometric analysis of a significant sample of Italian municipalities, the results confirm the presence of an inverse relation between the scale and the average cost of the service. This finding is important considering that as the size of the service increases by 1%, the average cost of MSW management services decreases by 0.46% nationwide. From the results, the inverse relation between service scale and costs can also be inferred to persist even under different hypotheses, as confirmed by our scenario analysis.

To fine-tune the analysis and provide useful insights that benefit managers and local administrators, a simulation has been carried out for the city of Milan by testing whether the service costs were lower when run by a single firm compared to when run by four different firms. The evidence suggests that MSW management is more efficient when carried out by a single firm given the industry structure, resource and labour force optimisation, and lower transaction costs, which, in certain circumstances, overcome the efficiency gains of the market, envisaged by economic theory.

The simulation revealed that dividing the city into sub-areas may lead to diseconomies, thus undermining economic efficiency and general service quality and creating undesirable consequences for social welfare and the equal treatment of citizens. Therefore, there are cases where contracting authorities shall decide that it is not appropriate to divide the contract into lots due to the risk of rendering the execution of the contract excessively technically difficult or expensive and because coordinating the different contractors could risk undermining the proper execution of the contract to the detriment of equity and quality.

This study has certain limitations. The results are extendable and relevant to other cities only when the spatial and socio-economic characteristics are comparable given that the factors used to identify whether a single firm is more efficient can lead to varied results in cities characterised by non-homogeneous conditions or in larger multi-centric cities. In fact, the land of the city of Milan is flat, with an altitude of approximately 130 metres, on an administrative area of approximately 181.7 square kilometres, with a population of slightly less than 1.4 million inhabitants: 7,315 inhabitants per square kilometre. Consequently, a very different situation with respect, for example, to Rome: approximately 2,860,889 residents in 1,285 km2, 2.226 inhabitants per square kilometre and varied land characteristics. In such urban conditions, the results in terms of optimal business organisation may significantly change, preventing our results from being extended to geographically significantly different cities.

In the context of large cities, both the advantages of dividing the municipal area into smaller sub-areas – or the service into more lots – to facilitate the potential entry of smaller operators and the a priori advantages related to the existence of economies of scale need to be further studied and contextualised to avoid a strategic drift in municipal waste service planning.

The future research should focus on two topics. First, the activities that comprise waste management services should be broken down to investigate the opportunities presented by and costs of alternative forms of management for each sub-service according to scale and other exogenous factors. Second, provided that cross-sectional studies struggle due to sampling reasons, an analysis of the impact of economies of scale and scope in large cities is needed using case study approaches.

Figures

Possible service configurations

Figure 1

Possible service configurations

Waste management chain

Figure 2

Waste management chain

Correlation between the main variables and their relative distribution

Figure 3

Correlation between the main variables and their relative distribution

Scale and costs of MSW management

Figure 4

Scale and costs of MSW management

Average cost reduction due to scale

Figure 5

Average cost reduction due to scale

Taxonomy of sub-services classified by scope that make up the municipal waste management service examined in this article

Figure A1

Taxonomy of sub-services classified by scope that make up the municipal waste management service examined in this article

Variables

VariableLabelNMeanSDMinMax
TCCost of waste management per kg4,16933.2811.3611.9965.36
DCCost of sorted waste management per kg3,43820.6512.087.80107.80
UCCost of unsorted waste management per kg4,04738.3324.1911.24258.75
mswMunicipal waste generated (th)4,1585.4333.200.041691.89
sorPercentage of sorted waste4,16366.5917.472.8797.48
areaMunicipality km24,16941.2457.260.671287.39
densPopulation density4,169419.41788.212.2911675.83
altAltitude4,169300.05272.261.001816.00
coastCoastal municipality4,1690.170.370.001.00

Source(s): Author's creation

Econometric analysis

Model 1 TCModel 2 SCModel 3 UC
(Intercept)5.664***3.868***1.789***
(0.067)(0.112)(0.110)
Municipal waste generated−0.430***−0.618***−0.448***
(0.016)(0.026)(0.025)
Municipality km20.477***0.663***0.426***
(0.017)(0.027)(0.027)
Percentage of sorted waste−0.114***−0.414***0.439***
(0.013)(0.022)(0.021)
Population density0.407***0.606***0.367***
(0.016)(0.027)(0.027)
Altitude0.024***0.025***−0.005
(0.004)(0.006)(0.006)
Coastal municipality0.314***0.245***0.271***
(0.013)(0.021)(0.021)
N4,1523,4304,031
R20.3220.2950.198

Note(s): ***p < 0.001; **p < 0.01; *p < 0.05. Logarithms (except coastal municipality being a dummy)

Source(s): Author's creation

Opportunities of alternative scenarios

One firm. Figure 1 (a)More firms. Figure 1 (b, c, d)
  • Economies of scope

  • Coordination among the grantor and the concessionaire

  • Reduction of transaction costs resulting from fewer contracts

  • Equity and same quality of the service provided to citizens

  • Technological innovation given that positive linkages between size and innovation can occur in presence of high sunk costs

  • Quality standardisation that derives from the same organisation of inputs

  • Economies of scale especially in the collection phase

  • Competitive environment

  • Lower bargaining power of the concessionaire

  • More symmetric information and performance comparison among competitors

  • Low market concentration that if not properly regulated may lead to inefficiency in the medium-term due to the loss of market attractivity for potential efficient firms

  • Reduced risks of market foreclosure

  • level playing field

Source(s): Author's creation

Reiteration of model

Sub-data20151053Sample
[1]−0.31372−0.33094−0.31634−0.37158−0.37862−0.42978
[2]−0.32611−0.37511−0.43249−0.40171−0.44498
[3]−0.48359−0.41878−0.43975−0.48186−0.54488
[4]−0.38682−0.37266−0.35493−0.47869
[5]−0.37478−0.40508−0.48093−0.56061
[6]−0.52579−0.4231−0.4811
[7]−0.30548−0.52618−0.41572
[8]−0.40513−0.43573−0.54459
[9]−0.4777−0.48171−0.52883
[10]−0.45353−0.38149−0.61994
[11]−0.45757−0.57469
[12]−0.5055−0.52394
[13]−0.35008−0.46211
[14]−0.55512−0.58765
[15]−0.58066−0.68303
[16]−0.55199
[17]−0.46168
[18]−0.57222
[19]−0.54199
[20]−0.73681
Mean−0.46831−0.46548−0.46146−0.45889−0.45616−0.42978
Mean 3−0.37448−0.37494−0.39619−0.41838
Mean 5−0.377−0.38051−0.40489
Mean 10−0.43344
N2082784178341,390
Annex 2

References

AGCM - Italian Competition Authority. (2016), IC49 - Municipal Solid Waste Management inquiry [IC49 -Indagine Conoscitiva Sui Rifiuti Urbani], Roma, available at: https://www.agcm.it/dotcmsCustom/getDominoAttach?urlStr=192.168.14.10:8080/C12564CE0049D161/0/A6CD7E5E68FE8B25C1257F5B004DC5E4/$File/IC49.pdf

Allesch, A. and Brunner, P.H. (2014), “Assessment methods for solid waste management: a literature review”, Waste Management and Research, Vol. 32 No. 6, pp. 461-473.

Avilés-Palacios, C. and Rodríguez-Olalla, A. (2021), “The sustainability of waste management models in circular economies”, Sustainability, Vol. 13 No. 13, doi: 10.3390/su13137105.

Bartolacci, F., Del Gobbo, R., Paolini, A. and Soverchia, M. (2019), “Efficiency in waste management companies: a proposal to assess scale economies”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 148, pp. 124-131, Elsevier.

Beccarello, M. and Di Foggia, G. (2016), “Economic analysis of EU Strengthened packaging waste recycling targets”, Journal of Advanced Research in Law and Economics, Vol. 7 No. 8, pp. 1930-1941.

Bel, G. and Fageda, X. (2010), “Empirical analysis of solid management waste costs: some evidence from Galicia, Spain”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 54 No. 3, pp. 187-193, Elsevier.

Bel, G. and Sebő, M. (2020), “Introducing and enhancing competition to improve delivery of local services of solid waste collection”, Waste Management, Vol. 118, pp. 637-646, Elsevier.

Bel, G. and Sebő, M. (2021), “Watch your neighbor: strategic competition in waste collection and service quality”, Waste Management, Vol. 127, pp. 63-72.

Benito-López, B., Moreno-Enguix, M., del, R. and Solana-Ibañez, J. (2011), “Determinants of efficiency in the provision of municipal street-cleaning and refuse collection services”, Waste Management, Vol. 31 No. 6, pp. 1099-1108, Pergamon.

Beraha, A., Bingol, D., Ozkan-Canbolat, E. and Szczygiel, N. (2018), “The effect of strategic flexibility configurations on product innovation”, European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 129-140, Emerald Publishing.

Björklund, A., Dalemo, M. and Sonesson, U. (1999), “Evaluating a municipal waste management plan using orware”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 271-280.

Boggio, M. (2016), “From public to mixed ownership in local public services provision: an empirical analysis”, Local Government Studies, Vol. 42 No. 3, pp. 420-440, Routledge.

Bohm, R.A., Folz, D.H., Kinnaman, T.C. and Podolsky, M.J. (2010), “The costs of municipal waste and recycling programs”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 54 No. 11, pp. 864-871, Elsevier B.V.

Callan, S.J. and Thomas, J.M. (2001), “Economies of scale and scope: a cost analysis of municipal solid waste services”, Land Economics, Vol. 77 No. 4, pp. 548-560.

Cheung, S.N.S. (2016), “Economic organization and transaction costs”, in Vernengo, M., Perez Caldentey, E. and Jr, B.J.R. (Eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Palgrave Macmillan UK, London, pp. 1-5.

Chifari, R., Lo Piano, S., Matsumoto, S. and Tasaki, T. (2017), “Does recyclable separation reduce the cost of municipal waste management in Japan?”, Waste Management, Vol. 60, pp. 32-41, Pergamon.

Chu, Z., Wang, W., Zhou, A. and Huang, W.-C. (2019), “Charging for municipal solid waste disposal in Beijing”, Waste Management, Vol. 94, pp. 85-94, Pergamon.

Da Cruz, N.F., Simões, P. and Marques, R.C. (2014), “Costs and benefits of packaging waste recycling systems”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 85, pp. 1-4.

Darus, F., Mohd Zuki, H.I. and Yusoff, H. (2020), “The path to sustainability: understanding organisations' environmental initiatives and climate change in an emerging economy”, European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 29 No. 1, pp. 84-96, Emerald Publishing.

DaSilva, C.M. and Trkman, P. (2014), “Business model: what it is and what it is not”, Long Range Planning, Vol. 47 No. 6, pp. 379-389, Elsevier.

De Jaeger, S. and Rogge, N. (2013), “Waste pricing policies and cost-efficiency in municipal waste services: the case of Flanders”, Waste Management and Research, Vol. 31 No. 7, pp. 751-758.

De Jaeger, S., Eyckmans, J., Rogge, N. and Van Puyenbroeck, T. (2011), “Wasteful waste-reducing policies? The impact of waste reduction policy instruments on collection and processing costs of municipal solid waste”, Waste Management, Vol. 31 No. 7, pp. 1429-1440, Pergamon.

Di Foggia, G. and Beccarello, M. (2018), “Improving efficiency in the MSW collection and disposal service combining price cap and yardstick regulation: the Italian case”, Waste Management, Vol. 79, pp. 223-231, Elsevier.

Di Foggia, G. and Beccarello, M. (2020), “Drivers of municipal solid waste management cost based on cost models inherent to sorted and unsorted waste”, Waste Management, Vol. 114, pp. 202-214, Elsevier.

Di Foggia, G. and Beccarello, M. (2021), “Market structure of urban waste treatment and disposal: empirical evidence from the Italian industry”, Sustainability, Vol. 13, p. 7412, doi: 10.3390/su13137412.

Diaz-Farina, E., Díaz-Hernández, J.J. and Padrón-Fumero, N. (2020), “The contribution of tourism to municipal solid waste generation: a mixed demand-supply approach on the island of Tenerife”, Waste Management, Vol. 102, pp. 587-597, Pergamon.

Esmaeilian, B., Wang, B., Lewis, K., Duarte, F., Ratti, C. and Behdad, S. (2018), “The future of waste management in smart and sustainable cities: a review and concept paper”, Waste Management, Vol. 81, pp. 177-195.

European Commission (2022), “Services of general economic interest”, EUR-Lex, European Union, available at: https://eur-lex.europa.eu/EN/legal-content/glossary/services-of-general-economic-interest.html

Garrido-Vega, P., Sacristán-Díaz, M., Moyano-Fuentes, J. and Alfalla-Luque, R. (2021), “The role of competitive environment and strategy in the supply chain's agility, adaptability and alignment capabilities”, European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Emerald Publishing, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print, doi: 10.1108/EJMBE-01-2021-0018.

Goddard, H.C. (1995), “The benefits and costs of alternative solid waste management policies”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 13 Nos 3-4, pp. 183-213, Elsevier.

Greco, G., Allegrini, M., Del Lungo, C., Gori Savellini, P. and Gabellini, L. (2015), “Drivers of solid waste collection costs. Empirical evidence from Italy”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 106, pp. 364-371, Elsevier.

Guerrini, A., Carvalho, P., Romano, G., Cunha Marques, R. and Leardini, C. (2017), “Assessing efficiency drivers in municipal solid waste collection services through a non-parametric method”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 147, pp. 431-441, Elsevier.

Jacobsen, R., Buysse, J. and Gellynck, X. (2013), “Cost comparison between private and public collection of residual household waste: multiple case studies in the Flemish region of Belgium”, Waste Management, Vol. 33 No. 1, pp. 3-11, Elsevier.

Kaza, S., Yao, L., Bhada-Tata, P. and Van Woerden, F. (2018), What a Waste 2.0: A Global Snapshot of Solid Waste Management to 2050, The World Bank, Washington, DC. doi: 10.1596/978-1-4648-1329-0.

Kinnaman, T.C. (2009), “The economics of municipal solid waste management”, Waste Management, Vol. 29 No. 10, pp. 2615-2617.

Klaes, M. (2016), “Transaction costs, history of”, in Vernengo, M., Perez Caldentey, E. and Rosser, B.J. (Eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Palgrave Macmillan UK, London, pp. 1-7.

Llanquileo-Melgarejo, P. and Molinos-Senante, M. (2021), “Evaluation of economies of scale in eco-efficiency of municipal waste management: an empirical approach for Chile”, Environmental Science and Pollution Research, Vol. 28 No. 22, pp. 28337-28348.

Lombrano, A. (2009), “Cost efficiency in the management of solid urban waste”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 53 No. 11, pp. 601-611, Elsevier.

lo Storto, C. (2021), “Effectiveness-efficiency nexus in municipal solid waste management: a non-parametric evidence-based study”, Ecological Indicators, Vol. 131, 108185.

Marashlian, N. and El-Fadel, M. (2005), “The effect of food waste disposers on municipal waste and wastewater management”, Waste Management and Research, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 20-31, SAGE Publications STM.

Mazzanti, M., Montini, A. and Zoboli, R. (2008), “Municipal waste generation and socioeconomic drivers. Evidence from comparing Northern and Southern Italy”, The Journal of Environment and Development, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 51-69.

Mugoni, E., Nyagadza, B. and Hove, P.K. (2023), “Green reverse logistics technology impact on agricultural entrepreneurial marketing firms' operational efficiency and sustainable competitive advantage”, Sustainable Technology and Entrepreneurship, Vol. 2 No. 2, 100034.

Niehans, J. (2016), “Transaction costs”, in Vernengo, M., Perez Caldentey, E. and Rosser, B.J. (Eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Palgrave Macmillan UK, London, pp. 1-6.

Passarini, F., Vassura, I., Monti, F., Morselli, L. and Villani, B. (2011), “Indicators of waste management efficiency related to different territorial conditions”, Waste Management, Vol. 31 No. 4, pp. 785-792, Elsevier.

Pérez-López, G., Prior, D., Zafra-Gómez, J.L. and Plata-Díaz, A.M. (2016), “Cost efficiency in municipal solid waste service delivery. Alternative management forms in relation to local population size”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 255 No. 2, pp. 583-592.

Plata-Díaz, A.M., Zafra-Gómez, J.L., Pérez-López, G. and López-Hernández, A.M. (2014), “Alternative management structures for municipal waste collection services: the influence of economic and political factors”, Waste Management, Vol. 34 No. 11, pp. 1967-1976.

Roy, H., Islam, M.S., Haque, S. and Riyad, M.H. (2022), “Electronic waste management scenario in Bangladesh: policies, recommendations, and case study at Dhaka and Chittagong for a sustainable solution”, Sustainable Technology and Entrepreneurship, Vol. 1 No. 3, 100025.

Sarra, A., Mazzocchitti, M. and Rapposelli, A. (2017), “Evaluating joint environmental and cost performance in municipal waste management systems through data envelopment analysis: scale effects and policy implications”, Ecological Indicators, Vol. 73, doi: 10.1016/j.ecolind.2016.10.035.

Sarra, A., Mazzocchitti, M. and Nissi, E. (2020), “Optimal regulatory choices in the organization of solid waste management systems: empirical evidence and policy implications”, Environmental Science and Policy, Vol. 114 April, pp. 436-444, Elsevier.

Simões, P., Cruz, N.F. and Marques, R.C. (2012), “The performance of private partners in the waste sector”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 29 No. 30, pp. 214-221, Elsevier.

Soukopová, J., Vaceková, G. and Klimovský, D. (2017), “Local waste management in the Czech Republic: limits and merits of public-private partnership and contracting out”, Utilities Policy, Vol. 48, pp. 201-209, Elsevier.

Stevens, B.J. (1978), “Scale, market structure, and the cost of refuse collection”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 60 No. 3, pp. 438-448, The MIT Press.

Swart, J. and Groot, L. (2015), “Waste management alternatives: (Dis)economies of scale in recovery and decoupling”, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Vol. 94, pp. 43-55, Elsevier.

Tickner, G. and Mcdavid, J.C. (1986), “Effects of scale and market structure on the costs of Residential solid waste collection in Canadian cities”, Public Finance Quarterly, Vol. 14 No. 4, pp. 371-393, SAGE Publications.

Tisserant, A., Pauliuk, S., Merciai, S., Schmidt, J., Fry, J., Wood, R. and Tukker, A. (2017), “Solid waste and the circular economy: a global analysis of waste treatment and waste footprints”, Journal of Industrial Ecology, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 628-640.

Walls, M. (2005), “How local governments structure contracts with private firms: economic theory and evidence on solid waste and recycling contracts”, Public Works Management and Policy, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 206-222.

Wowrzeczka, B. (2021), “City of waste—importance of scale”, Sustainability. doi: 10.3390/su13073909.

Zhang, X., Wu, Y., Skitmore, M. and Jiang, S. (2015), “Sustainable infrastructure projects in balancing urban-rural development: towards the goal of efficiency and equity”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 107, pp. 445-454, Elsevier.

Zorpas, A.A. (2020), “Strategy development in the framework of waste management”, Science of the Total Environment, Vol. 716, 137088, Elsevier B.V.

Corresponding author

Giacomo Di Foggia can be contacted at: giacomo.difoggia@unimib.it

Related articles